Blog | 11 Feb 2021

We are not all Keynesians

Globally, human behaviour had already seen significant changes in recent years, and these changes have accelerated during the pandemic. Albeit painful and unwanted, the pandemic has arguably provided an opportune moment for creative destruction to take its course and for the private sector to develop industries that better suit the wants and needs of people. As such, one of the risks of pushing a Keynesian theme is that it will serve to support some industries that policy-makers have decided upon. As an aside, those decisions would most likely be accompanied by lobbying and uncompetitive endeavours, although even if we assume benevolence, the government cannot know the needs of people better than they do themselves, and cannot act more efficiently than the market mechanism. Invariably, this would hinder the development of new industries.

At the same time, the government’s increased role in the economy would be accompanied by wide budget deficits, and rising public debts. This can only be paid for through higher taxes or inflation, both of which have the same negative consequences for future generations. At some stage or another, the average person would need to pay for Keynesian excesses. So although the Keynesian policies would limit the losses in aggregate demand in the near term, it may very well come at the cost of bigger losses for future generations.

Another concern (from a non-Keynesian at least) is whether government investment would be productive. One sector in which government investment can still make a big difference is renewable energy. Apart from that though, most of the advanced world has enough infrastructure, social safety nets and security forces to make lives safe and comfortable for its people. Instead, a more productive outcome might be if advanced economy governments use their wealth (and their ability to raise funds at little cost) to invest in developing economies where infrastructure is inadequate to support economic growth. The entire global economy could be shifted to a higher level if the infrastructural challenges of poor countries can be solved. The caveat here is that corrupt governments in poor countries should have no control over the investments and therefore industries benefiting should be completely privatised as a prerequisite for investment. Unfortunately, that might be an impossible ask.

You may be interested in

Post

VAT gap in the EU: 2024 report

The EU VAT Gap 2024 report offers an extensive analysis of the value-added tax (VAT) compliance and policy gaps across the EU. As part of a larger consortium, Oxford Economics analysed the discrepancy between the theoretical VAT Total Tax Liability (VTTL) and actual revenue collected, providing insights into compliance inefficiencies and policy-induced revenue losses.

Find Out More

Post

The Economic Contribution of International Spirits in Hong Kong

This report presents an assessment of international spirits’ contribution to the Hong Kong economy. It explores how rebalancing the tax structure on spirits towards a specific tax system could potentially provide a more effective tax policy instrument and enable Hong Kong to benefit further from the sector’s economic contribution.

Find Out More

Post

Eurozone: Why food prices are a channel for more frequent supply shocks

More frequent adverse supply shocks mean eurozone inflation is likely to be more volatile and possibly higher on average in the future. Food prices are a key channel through which these global shocks will be transmitted, according to our analysis. We provide a quantitative assessment of the impact of a wide range of supply shocks on eurozone inflation.

Find Out More