Blog | 19 May 2021

Why critics of President Biden’s American Rescue Plan are getting it wrong

With the American Rescue Plan, US President Biden is implementing a stimulus program of historic proportions. Coming on top of the highest debt-to-GDP ratio the US has ever seen, this is raising fears that the government could be spending too much, entailing more negative than positive consequences. Even economists that had, until now, very prominently called for increases in public spending seem to be intimidated by the magnitudes of money now involved (most notably former Treasury Secretary Larry Summers and former IMF Chief Economist Olivier Blanchard).

Fears about this unparalleled spending splurge fall into two classic categories—the negative consequences in the short run, and those of the long term. In the short- to medium run, the economy could be running “too hot,” forcing the Fed to react early and quickly to avoid run-away inflation. This in turn could destabilise asset markets, whose high valuations heavily rely on ultra-low interest rates and continued QE (as we have argued in a previous blog post). In the long-run, the surging debt-to-GDP ratio could become unsustainable once interest rates rise, raising the spectre of a US default.

But what these arguments miss is that the short- and long-run are not independent of each other. This is a fallacy that has permeated economic thought for ages, where generations of economists have been taught that long-run growth and short-run business cycles can be studied independently. According to standard theory, the forces behind long-run growth are determined by the supply side, with engines such as productivity growth, population growth, and education. By contrast, business cycles are mostly driven by demand-side factors. Once a business-cycle shock peters out, the economy supposedly trends back to its long-run growth path.

This two-fold structure underlies many modern macroeconomic workhorse models used by central banks and academics alike (one exception being the Oxford Economics Global Economic Model). But it may very well be wrong, and this is where Biden’s stimulus package comes in. As we have argued early on, the American Rescue Plan is likely to run the economy hot, but this is fully intended. Inflation will probably overshoot 2% for several years, but that’s in line with the Fed’s new mandate, with run-away inflation a very remote possibility. So all the traffic lights for activity are on green, flashing a clear signal to companies to go for it: hire and invest all you can, as the next decade is looking great. The government is doing a huge experiment trying to align expectations of the private sector and thereby shape a new long-run equilibrium. The spending plans are meant to simultaneously push the equilibrium rate of unemployment down, push investment up, and raise growth expectations.

Hence, by running the economy hot in the short- to medium-run the US government is increasing long-run growth potential, thereby making the debt-to-GDP ratio sustainable and limiting inflationary pressures. Larry Summers is right in arguing that there are multiple equilibria in the future. But by arguing that overspending may push the economy towards an unsustainable debt-to-GDP ratio he may be understating the amount to which the numerator (GDP) could rise in the long-run, because he employs models that insufficiently account for the impact of demand-side stimulus on long-run potential growth.

Spring bloom will turn into a summer boom

If Biden succeeds in his huge macroeconomic experiment—and he well may—this would not only re-establish the US as the leading global player, but also cause a paradigm shift in our economic thinking.

You may be interested in

Post

Tariff whiplash starting to cause US supply-chain stress

Tariff threats and heightened trade policy uncertainty began causing stress in supply chains.

Find Out More

Post

US PCE nowcast shows no slowdown in price pressures

Despite weaker-than-expected gains in headline consumer and producer prices in February, the source data that feed into the PCE deflator show few signs of a slowdown, something that won't sit well with the Federal Reserve as the boost from tariffs is still to come.

Find Out More

Post

Parsing US federal job cuts by metro

Cuts to the Federal government workforce, which we estimate to be 200,000 in 2025, will have a modest impact nationally, but more significant implications for the Washington, DC metropolitan economy as it accounts for 17% of all non-military federal jobs in the US.

Find Out More

Post

US inflation expectations are key to the Fed’s outlook this year

Tariffs typically result in a one-off rise in the level of prices.

Find Out More